Econ 50: Economic Analysis I

Problem Set 2: Constrained Optimization when Calculus Works

Due Saturday, October 4 at 11pm on Gradescope


Exercises 2.1 and 2.2 may be done after Monday’s lecture; 2.3 and 2.4 correspond to Wednesday; and the rest are based on Friday’s lecture.

At a minimum, you should do 2.1, 2.3, 2.5, and 2.6. Students in 50Q should do 2.2 and 2.8. The most important exercises are the last ones!


Monotonicity and Convexity

Sarah enjoys eating both apples (good 1) and oranges (good 2). Her preferences over these two goods are strictly monotonic and strictly convex. Remember the formal definition of convexity: if preferences are strictly convex, then if a consumer is indifferent between two bundles, she prefers a convex combination of those bundles to either bundle.

Sarah is choosing between the following bundles:

Bundle Apples Oranges
$A$ 2 6
$B$ 6 6
$C$ 4 4
$D$ 2 2
$E$ 6 2

Is each of the following statements true or false? Briefly explain.

Because $B$ has more of both goods than $D$, it must be that $B \succ D$.

Because $C$ is a convex combination of $B$ and $D$, it must be that $C \succ D$ and $C \succ B$.

Because $B$ has the same number of apples as $E$, it is possible that $B \sim E$.

Because $C$ has more oranges than $E$, but fewer apples, it is possible that $C \succ E$ or $E \succ C$.

Because $C$ is a convex combination of $A$ and $E$, it must be that $C \succ E$ and $C \succ A$.

Suppose Sarah tells you she’s indifferent between bundles $A$ and $E$. Using that information, sketch a possible indifference map showing the indifference curves passing through each of the five bundles.

Sarah’s friend Katrina also likes apples and oranges, but her preferences aren’t quite the same: she prefers more fruits than less, but only cares about the total number of fruits she eats, not which kind they are. (Therefore, for example, she would be indifferent between eating 4 apples, 4 oranges, or 2 of each.) Repeat part (b) for Katrina and draw her indifference curves passing through each of the five bundles. Are her preferences strictly monotonic? Are they strictly convex?


One Function to Rule Them All

The Constant Elasticity of Substitution (CES) utility function takes the form \(u(x_1,x_2) = \left(x_1^r + x_2^r\right)^\frac{1}{r}\) where the parameter $r$ measures the “substitutability” of goods 1 and 2.

Solve for the marginal rate of substitution (MRS) of this utility function.

What is the MRS when $r = 1$? What kinds of preferences does this represent in that case?

What is the MRS when $r = 0$? What kinds of preferences does this represent in that case? Can you write an equivalent utility function (i.e., one that represents the same preferences) using a different functional form? Note that if you actually try to find $MU_1$ and $MU_2$ when $r = 0$, you need to use L’Hôpital’s rule…but that’s beyond the scope of this assignment. It’s fine for this case to just plug $r=0$ into the expression for the MRS you found in part (a).

(For 50Q only.) What is the MRS, in the limit, as $r \rightarrow -\infty$? What kinds of preferences does this represent in that case? Can you write an equivalent utility function (i.e., one that represents the same preferences) using a different functional form?


Changing Budget Sets

Each of the following scenarios describes a “before” and “after” situation. In each case, using a single diagram clearly indicate:

How far would you go for bananas?

Scarce resources, unlimited desires

Effect of a gas tax


Kinked budget sets

Sometimes a budget set isn’t a simple straight line. Here are some examples of budget sets with kinks that you’ll encounter during your studies of economics. In each, clearly draw the budget constraint. Hint: when applicable, think of the extreme cases in which someone consumes as much good 1 as they can, or as much good 2 as they can, and what’s happening at any “kink” in the constraint.

A token gift

Used stuff always goes for cheaper

The “Donut Hole”


Cobb-Douglas Optimization with the Lagrange Method

Consider the Cobb-Douglas utility function \(u(x_1,x_2) = x_1^{\alpha}x_2^{1-\alpha}\) where $0 < \alpha < 1$.

Use the Lagrange method to find the utility-maximizing bundle, as a function of $\alpha$, if $p_1 = 6$, $p_2 = 2$, and $m = 48$.

Interpret your results. How do the optimal choices of $x_1$ and $x_2$ change as $\alpha$ changes?

Plot the budget line, indifference curve, and optimal bundle if $\alpha = \frac{ 1 }{ 4 }$.


Quasilinear Optimization with the Lagrange Method

Consider the function \(u(x_1,x_2) = 20 \ln x_1 + x_2\)

Use the Lagrange method to find the maximum of this function, subject to the constraint \(x_1 + x_2 = m\) as a function of the constant $m$: that is, find $x_1^\star(m)$ and $x_2^\star(m)$. You may assume that $m > 0$.

Now suppose we were to add another constraint that $x_1 \ge 0$ and $x_2 \ge 0$. In other words, the goal now is to find the highest value of $u(x_1,x_2)$ along the segment connecting the points $(0,m)$ and $(m,0)$. What are the solution functions $x_1^\star(m)$ and $x_2^\star(m)$ now?


Lagrange with Linear Functions

Suppose you were trying to maximize the perfect-substitutes utility function \(u(x_1,x_2) = ax_1 + bx_2\) subject to the constraint \(x_1 + 2x_2 = 12\) where $a$ and $b$ are strictly positive constants.

Set up the Lagrangian of this problem, and find its first-order conditions.

In your own words, explain why the Lagrange method will never work to find a unique solution to this problem.

Suppose, as in the last question, that we further constrain the solution to be in the first quadrant (i.e., $x_1 \ge 0$ and $x_2 \ge 0$). What would be the solution to the maximization problem, as a function of $a$ and $b$?


Can’t Buy Me One (Harmonica)

This question is only required for 50Q students.

Jake and Elwood are looking to buy some instruments as they launch their new band. They need to buy some number of harmonicas ($x_1$) and saxophones ($x_2$) for their performances.

While Ray’s Music Exchange is perfectly willing to sell these goods in continuous quantities ($x_1=3.14$ harmonicas is perfectly acceptable), they have a somewhat annoying store policy: every customer must buy at least 2 harmonicas in order to make purchases at the store. That is, Jake and Elwood can only walk out the door with a bundle where $x_1\ge 2$. Ray has set a price of $p_1$ for harmonicas and $p_2$ for saxophones. You can assume that Jake and Elwood will choose to purchase positive quantities of both goods.

Jake and Elwood have $m$ dollars to spend, and gain utility \(u(x_1, x_2) = x_1^\alpha x_2^{1-\alpha}\) from purchasing the two goods.


What is the objective function in this setting? What are the constraints?

(Hint: for the sake of later subproblems, you might want to take a certain monotonic transformation of the utility like we discussed in section to make the algebra easier.)

Write the full Lagrangian associated with this problem. Give an intuition for the interpretation of any Lagrange multipliers which appear in the equation (max 2 sentences, shorter is better).

Derive the (first order) conditions for optimality, as well as any complementary-slackness conditions.

What is Jake and Elwood’s optimal consumption $(x_1^\star,x_2^\star)$ when the $x_1\ge2$ constraint does not bind? What is the value of the Lagrange multiplier on the $x_1\ge2$ constraint?

What is Jake and Elwood’s optimal consumption $(x_1^\star,x_2^\star)$ when the $x_1\ge2$ constraint does bind? What is the value of the Lagrange multiplier on the $x_1\ge2$ constraint?

Should we expect the constraint to bind when $m$ is larger, or smaller? Explain intuitively.