EconGraphs Logo BETA
Note: This work is under development and has not yet been professionally edited.
If you catch a typo or error, or just have a suggestion, please submit a note here. Thanks!
Chapter 13 / Friday, October 25 | Demand Functions and Demand Curves

13.2 Demand Functions for Cobb-Douglas Utility Functions


For a generic Cobb-Douglas utility function \(u(x_1,x_2) = x_1^a x_2^b\) or equivalently, \(u(x_1,x_2) = a \ln x_1 + b \ln x_2\) the MRS is \(MRS = {ax_2 \over bx_1}\) It’s easy to see that all the conditions for using the Lagrange method are met: the MRS is infinite when $x_1 = 0$, zero when $x_2 = 0$, and smoothly descends along any budget line. Therefore, to find the optimal bundle, we will set the MRS equal to the price ratio and plug the result back into the budget constraint.

Setting the MRS equal to the price ratio $p_1/p_2$ gives us the tangency condition \(\begin{aligned} MRS &= {p_1 \over p_2}\\ {ax_2 \over bx_1} &= {p_1 \over p_2}\\ x_2 &= {b \over a}{p_1 \over p_2}x_1 \end{aligned}\) Plugging this back into the budget constraint, we can solve for $x_1$: \(\begin{aligned} p_1x_1 + p_2x_2 &= m\\ p_1x_1 + p_2\left[{b \over a}{p_1 \over p_2}x_1\right] &= m\\ ap_1x_1 + bp_1x_1 &= am\\ p_1x_1 &= {a \over a + b}m\\ x_1^\star(p_1,p_2) &= {a \over a + b}{m \over p_1} \end{aligned}\) and therefore \(x_2^\star = {b \over a}{p_1 \over p_2}x_1^\star = {b \over a + b}{m \over p_2}\) Intuitively, this means you spend fraction ${a \over a+b}$ of your income on good 1, and fraction ${b \over a + b}$ on good 2.

Try playing around with the graph below to see how $a$, $b$, $p_1$, $p_2$, and $m$ affect the optimal choice:

Previous: Introduction
Next: Demand Functions for Perfect Complements
Copyright (c) Christopher Makler / econgraphs.org