EconGraphs Logo BETA
Note: This work is under development and has not yet been professionally edited.
If you catch a typo or error, or just have a suggestion, please submit a note here. Thanks!
Chapter 6 / Thursday, April 17 | Competitive Exchange Equilibrium

6.3 Interpreting the Equilibrium Price Ratio


Interpreting the Equilibrium Price: Scarcity and Preferences

In the previous example, the two agents had Cobb-Douglas utility functions which put equal weight on each good, and there was twice as much good 1 as good 2; and the price ratio worked out so that the price of good 2 was twice that of good 1 (i.e. $p_1/p_2 = 1/2$). This is a feature of competitive equilibrium with Cobb-Douglas preferences, which can be used to illustrate some nice aspects of how the price ratio in competitive equilibrium relates to agents’ relative preferences for the two goods and the goods’ relative scarcity. To show why, we’ll have to do a bit of algebra.

Let’s go back to looking at both $p_1$ and $p_2$. Suppose each agent has normalized Cobb-Douglas preferences of the form \(u(x_1,x_2) = \alpha \ln x_1 + (1-\alpha) \ln x_2\) As we’ve shown many times, this means that each agent will spend fraction $\alpha$ of their income — in this case, the value of their endowment — on good 1, so their gross demand for good 1 will be \(x_1^* = \alpha \left ({p_1e_1 + p_2e_2 \over p_1}\right) = \alpha e_1 + \alpha e_2 \times {p_2 \over p_1}\) Subtracting $e_1$ from both sides, we can see that their net demand for good 1 is \(x_1^* - e_1 = -(1-\alpha)e_1 + \alpha e_2 \times {p_2 \over p_1}\) Now suppose that agent A’s value of $\alpha$ is $a$, while agent B’s value of $\alpha$ is $b$: \(\begin{aligned}u^A(x_1^A,x_2^A) &= a \ln x_1^A + (1-a) \ln x_2^A\\u^B(x_1^B,x_2^B) &= b \ln x_1^B + (1-b) \ln x_2^B\end{aligned}\) If we again assume that A is the supplier and B is the demander, A’s net supply and B’s net demand are given by \(\begin{aligned}s_1^A(p) &= (1-a)e_1^A - ae_2^A \times {p_2 \over p_1}\\d_1^B(p) &= -(1-b)e_1^B + be_2^B \times {p_2 \over p_1}\end{aligned}\) Equating these and solving for the price ratio $p_1/p_2$ gives us \(\begin{aligned} (1-a)e_1^A - ae_2^A \times {p_2 \over p_1} &= -(1-b)e_1^B + be_2^B \times {p_2 \over p_1}\\ (1-a)e_1^A + (1-b)e_1^B &= {p_2 \over p_1}\left(ae_2^A + be_2^B\right)\\ {p_1 \over p_2} &= {ae_2^A + be_2^B \over (1-a)e_1^A + (1-b)e_1^B} \end{aligned}\) OK, if you’ve tuned out because of all the algebra (full disclosure: I would!), just look at that last expression, which is our equilibrium price ratio in terms of four variables:

So how does the equilibrium price ratio change with each of these?

There are a few interesting special cases:

More generally, the equilibrium price ratio is jointly determined by the relative preferences for the two goods, and their relative scarcity. This result is also true for utility functions that aren’t Cobb-Douglas, but they’re not necessarily shown as clearly by the formula for the equilibrium price.

Note: I’m going to write a bit more for Thursday’s lecture, but wanted to publish these notes for now. Stay tuned! The quiz won’t cover anything else though… :)

Previous: Competitive Equilibrium
[ End of chapter ]
Copyright (c) Christopher Makler / econgraphs.org