EconGraphs Logo BETA
Note: This work is under development and has not yet been professionally edited.
If you catch a typo or error, or just have a suggestion, please submit a note here. Thanks!
Chapter 10 / Welfare Effects of a Price Change

10.2 The Relationship between Money and Utility: Indirect Utility and Expenditure Functions


To establish the relationship a consumer has between money and utility, we can ask two related questions:

The answer to the first question is the indirect utility function; the answer to the second is the expenditure function. As we’ll see, these are actually inverses of one another!

Indirect Utility Functions

The indirect utility function is a function of prices and income that describes the utility from the utility-maximizing bundle given those prices and income. That is, if a consumer has ordinary (“Marshallian”) demand functions \(x_1^\star(p_1,p_2,m)\) \(x_2^\star(p_1,p_2,m)\) then the indirect utility function $V(p_1,p_2,m)$ may be found by plugging those functions back into the utility function: \(V(p_1,p_2,m) = u(x_1^\star(p_1,p_2,m),x_2^\star(p_1,p_2,m))\) In other words, this asks: if a consumer with income $m$ faces prices $p_1$ and $p_2$, what is the maximum amount of utility they could achieve?

Indirect utility functions are often used when analyzing situations in which a consumer is choosing their income in a given situation: for example, choosing how much of their current income to save. In that case, the choice variable is the amount of money to spend in each period; so the utility they get will depend on how happy having an additional dollar to spend in each period would make them.

Expenditure Functions

The expenditure function is a function of prices and a utility level $U$ that describes the cost of the cost-minimizing way of achieving that utility given prices. That is, if a consumer has compensated (“Hicksian”) demand functions \(x_1^c(p_1,p_2,U)\) \(x_2^c(p_1,p_2,U)\) then the expenditure function $E(p_1,p_2,U)$ is the cost of the cost-minimizing bundle: \(E(p_1,p_2,U) = p_1 x_1^c(p_1,p_2,U)+ p_2 x_2^c(p_1,p_2,U)\) As we’ll see in the next section, expenditure functions are particularly useful in measuring changes in utility in terms of dollars. That is, if we’re interested in seeing how big of a deal some change in utility is, we can analyze the implied change in expenditure for a given set of prices.

Example: Cobb-Douglas

Suppose someone has Cobb-Douglas preferences of the form \(u(x_1,x_2) = (x_1 \times x_2)^{1 \over 2}\) We’ve shown many times that the ordinary demand functions for this utility function are \(x_1^\star(p_1,p_2,m) = \frac{m}{2p_1}\) \(x_2^\star(p_1,p_2,m) = \frac{m}{2p_2}\) To find the indirect utility function, we plug these optimized values back into the utility function: \(\begin{aligned} V(p_1,p_2,m) &= u(x_1^\star(p_1,p_2,m),x_2^\star(p_1,p_2,m))\\ &= (x_1^\star(p_1,p_2,m) \times x_2^\star(p_1,p_2,m))^{1 \over 2}\\ &= \left(\frac{m}{2p_1} \times \frac{m}{2p_2}\right)^{1 \over 2}\\ &= \tfrac{1}{2}p_1^{-{1 \over 2}}p_2^{-{1 \over 2}}m \end{aligned}\) Conversely, using the cost-minimization techniques we developed in the previous chapter, the compensated demand functions for this utility function are \(x_1^c(p_1,p_2,U) = p_1^{-{1 \over 2}}p_2^{1 \over 2}U\) \(x_2^c(p_1,p_2,U) = p_1^{1 \over 2}p_2^{-{1 \over 2}}U\) To find the expenditure function, we evaluate how much it would cost to buy the bundle $(x_1^c,x_2^c)$ at prices $p_1$ and $p_2$: \(\begin{aligned} E(p_1,p_2,U) &= p_1x_1^c(p_1,p_2,U) + p_2x_2^c(p_1,p_2,U)\\ &= p_1 \times p_1^{-{1 \over 2}}p_2^{1 \over 2}U + p_2 \times p_1^{1 \over 2}p_2^{-{1 \over 2}}U\\ &= 2p_1^{1 \over 2}p_2^{1 \over 2}U \end{aligned}\)

Relationship between indirect utility and expenditure functions

Let’s fix prices at $p_1 = p_2 = 1$, to focus on the relationship between money and utility. With these prices, the indirect utility function says that with money $m$, this consumer could achieve \(U = \tfrac{1}{2}m\) while the expenditure function says that to afford utility $U$, the consumer would need an income \(m = 2U\) In other words, these functions are just inverses of one another! Put another way, they each describe the relationship between utility and money. We can see why by looking at this graph:

The top graph shows the budget-line/indifference-curve diagram we’re so familiar with by now. If this is a utility maximization problem, the constraint is the budget line; if it’s representing a cost-minimization problem, the constraint is the indifference curve.

The bottom graph shows the relationship between money and utility, as described by the indirect utility and expenditure functions. The indirect utility function expresses $U$ as a function of $m$; the expenditure function expresses $m$ as a function of $U$. But they both describe the same relationship.

Notice the effect of a price change: an increase in the price of either good means you can’t afford as much happiness for any level of income, so the indirect utility function shifts down. Thought of another way, every level of utility gets more expensive, so the expenditure function shifts to the right.

We can use this framework to analyze how much money we would need to compensate someone, in the event of a price change, in order to allow them to achieve their initial utility. We call this amount the compensating variation.

Previous: Consumer Welfare
Next: Compensating Variation
Copyright (c) Christopher Makler / econgraphs.org