EconGraphs Logo BETA
Note: This work is under development and has not yet been professionally edited.
If you catch a typo or error, or just have a suggestion, please submit a note here. Thanks!
Chapter 7 / Utility Maximization Subject to a Budget Constraint

7.4 The Geometry of the Budget Line


In a situation with constant prices, the budget constraint is linear; so we call it a budget line. The equation of a budget line with two goods is \(p_1x_1 + p_2x_2 = m\) To analyze the geometry of the budget line, let’s think about its intercepts and slope. Let’s imagine that Jordan has 24 dollars to spend on apples (good 1) and bananas (good 2). If apples cost $p_1 = 4$ dollars per apple, and bananas cost $p_2 = 2$ dollars per banana, then if she spent all $€24$ on apples she could buy \(\overline x_1 = \frac{24\ \cancel{\text{dollars}}}{4\ \cancel{\text{dollars}}\text{/apple}} = 6 \text{ apples}\) Likewise, if she spent all $€24$ on bananas, she could buy \(\overline x_2 = \frac{24\ \cancel{\text{dollars}}}{2\ \cancel{\text{dollars}}\text{/banana}} = 12 \text{ bananas}\) These points represent the intercepts of her budget line. To think about the slope, let’s think of what happens as Jordan spends more money on apples and less on bananas. If she buys one more apple, it costs her 4 dollars; since each banana costs her 2 dollars, she has to buy two fewer bananas. Therefore the market prices of $p_1 = $4 dollars per apple and $p_2 = $2 dollars per banana allow her to trade off between those goods at a rate of 2 bananas for every apple; thus the slope of the budget line is 2 bananas per apple.

We can see these illustrated in the following graph. As always, feel free to play around with the parameters to see how the budget line’s slope and intercepts change:

Formulas for the budget line intercepts and slope

Let’s analyze the equations for her slope and intercept for general values of $p_1$, $p_2$, and $m$.

If Jordan spends all her money on good 1 (so $x_2 = 0$), then this becomes $p_1x_1 = m$, so her horizontal intercept is given by \(\overline x_1 = {m \over p_1}\) Likewise, if she spends all her money on good 2, we have $p_2x_2 = m$, so her vertical intercept is \(\overline x_2 = {m \over p_2}\) Finally, if we write the budget line as \(x_2 = {m \over p_2} - {p_1 \over p_2}x_1\) we can see that the slope of the budget line is \(\text{Slope of BL }=-{p_1 \over p_2}\)

Let’s pause a moment take a look at the units of this, just to be sure. We know $\overline x_1$ should be measured in units of good 1, $\overline x_2$ should be measured in units of good 2, and the slope of the budget line should be in units of good 2 per units of good 1. Jordan’s income $m$ is measured in dollars. The price $p_1$ is measured in dollars per unit of good 1, and the price $p_2$ is measured in dollars per unit of good 2. Therefore we can confirm that the equation for the horizontal intercept works out in terms of units: \(\overline x_1 = \frac{m\ \cancel{\text{dollars}}}{p_1\ \cancel{\text{dollars}}\text{/unit of good 1}} = \frac{m}{p_1} \text{ units of good 1}\) \(\overline x_2 = \frac{m\ \cancel{\text{dollars}}}{p_2\ \cancel{\text{dollars}}\text{/unit of good 2}} = \frac{m}{p_2} \text{ units of good 2}\) \(\text{Slope of BL} = -\frac{p_1\ \cancel{\text{dollars}}\text{/unit of good 1}}{p_2\ \cancel{\text{dollars}}\text{/unit of good 2}} = \frac{p_1}{p_2} \frac{\text{ units of good 2}}{\text{ units of good 1}}\) This is very important: the numbers we deal with in this course (almost) always have important units attached to them!

The price ratio as the opportunity cost of good 1

Remember that we referred to the MRT in positive terms when dealing with the slope of a PPF. Here, the slope of the budget constraint is $-p_1/p_2$; so the magnitude of the slope of the budget line (like the MRT) is the “price ratio” $p_1/p_2$. Just as the MRT measured the opportunity cost of producing another unit of good 1, so too the price ratio measures the opportunity cost of buying another unit of good 1, in terms of the amount of good 2 that must be given up.

In the above example, for example, we showed that if she bought one more apple for $p_1 = 4$ dollars, she had to give up 2 bananas, since they cost $p_2 = 2$ dollars per banana, so the opportunity cost of an apple was two bananas. More generally, if Jordan spent $p_1$ dollars to buy a unit of good 1, she would have to spend $p_1$ fewer dollars on good 2, thereby reducing her consumption of good 2 by $p_1/p_2$ units of good 2.

Shifts in the budget line

Since we’re interested in studying comparative statics, an important question to ask is how budget lines shift when prices or income change.

We know that the intercepts of the budget line are $\overline x_1 = m/p_1$ and $\overline x_2 = m/p_2$, and that the magnitude of the slope (in absolute value) is the price ratio $p_1/p_2$.

From these formulas, we can derive the following results:

Again, you can play with the graph above to see these for yourself.

Previous: The Budget Set
Next: The MRS and the Price Ratio
Copyright (c) Christopher Makler / econgraphs.org