EconGraphs Logo BETA
Note: This work is under development and has not yet been professionally edited.
If you catch a typo or error, or just have a suggestion, please submit a note here. Thanks!
Chapter 7 / Utility Maximization Subject to a Budget Constraint

7.5 The MRS and the Price Ratio


Now that we’ve established the nature of the constraint faced by a consumer, we can turn our attention to the consumer’s constrained optimization problem. The process for solving the constrained maximization problem subject to a budget line is exactly the same as it was for maximizing the utility subject to a PPF: only now we want to maximize $u(x_1,x_2)$ subject to the parameterized linear constraint $p_1x_1 + p_2x_2 = m$.

While the process is identical mathematically, the economic intuition behind this optimization problem is a bit new. In particular, the interpretation of the conditions comparing the MRS to the slope of the constraint now takes on a more specific meaning.

The “gravitational pull” argument from Chapter 5 went someting like this:

In the context of a consumer, the slope of the constraint is the price ratio $p_1/p_2$: so we can rephrase this as:

Visually, we can see this in the following diagram. Try dragging the bundle $X$ to the right and left along the budget line, and see how the MRS and the price ratio compare to one another:

When the $MRS > p_1/p_2$ at $X$, there is an area to the right of $X$ that is both affordable and preferred to $X$, and vice versa.

This comparison of the MRS to the price ratio is critical for understanding consumer behavior, so let’s take some time to look at it in detail. First, let’s think about what it means for the MRS to be greater than the price ratio — e.g. at some point to the left of the optimal bundle. There are three ways we might think about this:

Of course, the converse holds as well in all three interpretations: when $MRS < p_1/p_2$, the consumer is more willing to give up good 2 to get good 1 than the market requires; they derive less utility from good 1 than it costs, relative to good 2; and they got less “bang for the buck” from the last unit of good 1 they purchased than from the last unit of good 2; all of which would mean that they should shift their consumption from good 1 to good 2.

Previous: The Geometry of the Budget Line
Next: The Consumer's Optimal Choice
Copyright (c) Christopher Makler / econgraphs.org